Outlook 2016: Will liquidity dry up in
2016?
A
widespread anxiety about liquidity co-exists with trillions of euros pumped
into the markets by central banks. Daniel Ben-Ami explores the paradox
Will liquidity dry up in 2016? It
may not be a high profile public debate but it is a question preoccupying many
asset managers and international financial institutions at present. For the
time being, it seems to have replaced volatility as a primary concern for many
investors. It is also a topic that pension funds would do well to consider.
At a
glance
• There are widespread concerns
about the possibility of liquidity drying up in the financial markets.
• It is necessary to make a key distinction between funding liquidity and market liquidity.
• Tougher financial regulation seems to have played a key role in squeezing liquidity in recent years.
• Others also point to substantial structural changes within the financial markets as a reason for bouts of liquidity scarcity.
• It is necessary to make a key distinction between funding liquidity and market liquidity.
• Tougher financial regulation seems to have played a key role in squeezing liquidity in recent years.
• Others also point to substantial structural changes within the financial markets as a reason for bouts of liquidity scarcity.
At first sight, it is hard to
believe how such a scenario is even possible. Central banks have pumped
trillions of euros into the world economy since the advent of the global
financial crisis in 2008. With so much liquid capital sloshing around the
financial markets it is difficult to conceive how liquidity could dry up.
Yet there are certainly signs of
disruptions to liquidity in many markets. Much of the concern is focused on
emerging economy bond markets but it goes further than that. One of the most
high-profile episodes was the ‘taper tantrum’ in mid-2013 when Ben Bernanke,
then chairman of the US Federal Reserve, merely raised the possibility that
quantitative easing (QE) could be rolled back. Talk then was of the ‘fragile five’
– Brazil, India, Indonesia, South Africa and Turkey – which all had large
current account deficits. Their currencies weakened, stock markets plummeted
and bond yields surged. US bond yields also rose sharply in the aftermath.
Not that all the attention should be
focused on emerging markets. Even German Bunds – one of a select group of
government bonds to retain a AAA rating – have suffered problems with liquidity
over the past year. When yields spiked in April it became harder to make
trades, particularly in the futures markets.
The International Monetary Fund
(IMF) has also made public its concerns about disruptions to liquidity. In the
last few editions of its Global Financial Stability Report, its twice-yearly
scorecard on the state of the financial markets, it has devoted significant
space to the issue. It was also a topic of conversation at the annual meeting
of the IMF and World Bank in Lima, Peru, in October. No doubt the discussions
behind closed doors were more frank than the guarded public pronouncements.
Certainly the authorities have tried
to play down these fears. William Dudley, the president of the New York Fed,
gave a speech in September that was explicitly aimed at playing down these
fears. He argued that the evidence that liquidity has diminished markedly is
mixed and it is not clear, as some have alleged, that regulation is the primary
driver. Dudley also emphasised the importance of focusing on the robustness of
the financial system. The Bank of England has also published a blog post which
was designed to assuage fears about falling liquidity in the corporate bond
market in particular.
This article will attempt to gauge
the extent to which liquidity poses a problem for the financial markets. It
will focus particularly on what could be called the liquidity paradox: the
peculiar combination of an ample supply of liquidity from central banks with
apparent shortages in the market. It is a topic that is likely to prove a
significant concern over the coming year.
Definitions
A useful starting point for the investigation is to consider the meaning of liquidity. This is not sufficient to resolve the fundamental questions involved but it is necessary to eliminate common misconceptions. As Joachim Fels, a global economic adviser to Pimco, says: “Some of the confusion comes from the fact that people use the same word for very different concepts.”
A useful starting point for the investigation is to consider the meaning of liquidity. This is not sufficient to resolve the fundamental questions involved but it is necessary to eliminate common misconceptions. As Joachim Fels, a global economic adviser to Pimco, says: “Some of the confusion comes from the fact that people use the same word for very different concepts.”
It quickly becomes apparent that the
term ‘liquidity’ is a deeply ambiguous concept. It refers not to one thing but
at least two and arguably more. The names given to these different forms of
liquidity also vary. There is, therefore, enormous scope to argue at cross
purposes if the different concepts are not clarified.
On the one hand, there is market
liquidity or what could also be called micro liquidity. This refers to the ease
with which an asset can be bought and sold. So in a highly liquid market it
would be easy to buy and sell assets, whereas in an illiquid one it would be
difficult. Such matters are, of course, a central concern for market traders but
they have implications for fund managers too. For example, it can make it
harder for asset managers to either build up or exit large positions in
particular assets. It is in the market arena that the current concerns about
liquidity are focused.
Market liquidity is often measured
by the bid-ask spread (also known as bid-offer spread) on an asset. In a highly
liquid market, such spreads should be narrow – whereas, if there are problems,
such spreads would be expected to widen.
Figure 1 illustrates this trend in
relation to US Treasuries. The spread widens particularly in the midst of the
2008-09 financial crisis before falling back. It has also been on a broadly
upward trend over the past year. A similar graph of euro-zone sovereign bonds
would show Italian and French spreads spiking in 2011, with Spanish debt
spiking in early 2012.
Although such graphs are useful,
they are not infallible guides to the state of liquidity. It is possible for
liquidity to suddenly dry up, or ‘gap’, from what appears to be a relatively
easy state. For example, James Wood-Collins, the CEO of Record Currency
Management, says: “Emerging market currency has long had more of a propensity
to gap on unexpected news.” He goes on to explain how this trend has
exacerbated recently. “Historically we didn’t see much gapping in developed
market currencies but we’ve seen on four or five occasions this year when we
have seen that,” he says. The sudden surge in the Swiss franc on 15 January
when the Swiss National Bank removed the peg with the euro was a prime example.
There can also be anxiety about the possibility of liquidity drying up which is
not fully reflected in bid-ask spreads.
The other main form of liquidity is
often referred to as funding or macro liquidity. It essentially refers to the
amount of liquid capital circulating in the financial markets. This is the pool
to which the surplus liquidity provided by central banks contributes.
This semantic distinction between
market liquidity and funding liquidity helps clarify matters to a degree. It
should be clear that market liquidity is the subject of concern, whereas
funding liquidity, at least on the face of it, is ample.
However, this distinction, while
useful, does not resolve the matter. It still begs questions such as why market
liquidity should apparently be under threat when funding liquidity is so high.
More fundamentally, there are questions over what impact expansionary monetary
policy has on the markets and whether its effect is diminishing over time.
Many experts argue that there is no
necessary relationship between market liquidity and funding liquidity. Although
they are known by the same name, there is no direct connection between them.
Salman Ahmed, the chief strategist at Lombard Odier Investment Managers, says:
“There is no direct link, theoretical or conceptual, between these two.”
Pimco’s Joachim Fels points out that
the two can move in different directions. “You can imagine a situation where
you have a high market liquidity in the sense that it’s very easy to buy and
sell assets,” he says. “At the same time, you could be in an environment where
central banks are pursuing a tight monetary policy with high interest rates.”
That, of course, is the opposite scenario to what exists at present where
central bank liquidity seems high and market liquidity is relatively
low.
Regulation
The most common explanation for the recent propensity of the markets to liquidity shocks is the tightening of regulation since the 2008-09 financial crisis. The main focus is the banking sector where the regulatory authorities have made a concerted effort to ensure the banks take a more risk-averse stance. David Riley, the head of credit strategy at BlueBay Asset Management, says: “That regulatory response has significantly reduced the risk appetite that banks have and their ability to provide liquidity into the markets.” However, changes to the regulatory regime for insurers and mutual funds have also had an impact (see QE can work if conducted with the right logic).
The most common explanation for the recent propensity of the markets to liquidity shocks is the tightening of regulation since the 2008-09 financial crisis. The main focus is the banking sector where the regulatory authorities have made a concerted effort to ensure the banks take a more risk-averse stance. David Riley, the head of credit strategy at BlueBay Asset Management, says: “That regulatory response has significantly reduced the risk appetite that banks have and their ability to provide liquidity into the markets.” However, changes to the regulatory regime for insurers and mutual funds have also had an impact (see QE can work if conducted with the right logic).
Of course, the negative impact of
regulation in this respect immediately raises a dilemma. While the central
banks are trying to lubricate the markets, many financial regulators are, in
effect, doing the opposite. “QE is meant to incentivise lending, whereas the
new regulatory system is doing the reverse,” says Ahmed. It does not
necessarily follow that tighter regulation should be resisted but it does
illustrate the policy challenges faced by the authorities.
However, although regulation is
widely seen as important, many do not view it as the whole story. There is a
variety of explanations on why greater funding liquidity is not being
translated into higher market liquidity.
For Francesco Sandrini, the head of
multi asset securities solutions at Pioneer Investments, the answer lies in an imbalance
between the supply and demand for debt. QE and similar measures have pumped
huge amounts of liquidity into the financial markets but this is offset by a
growing demand for debt among governments themselves. “The decrease of leverage
in financial sector is more than compensated by increase in debt in the public
sector,” he says.
To make this argument, he points out
that, contrary to the public perception, the total amount of debt worldwide has
continued to increase since the financial crisis of 2008-09. However, over that
time its form has changed. With state bail-outs of financial institutions, the
level of financial debt has diminished but public debt has increased.
This shift, Sandrini argues, has
affected the money velocity. That is, in effect, the speed at which money is
transmitted from central banks to the real economy. Since the financial crisis,
and the advent of extraordinary monetary policy, this rate has slowed significantly
(figure 2).
Fels emphasises, instead, the money
multiplier (figure 3). This is a measure of the effectiveness of a given amount
of central bank intervention.
Fels points out that asset prices
were relatively low when central banks first started engaging in QE. But over
time, as asset prices have risen, it has become necessary for central banks to
spend more to have the same effect as before. “The first round of QE by the Fed
was so successful because asset prices were rock-bottom,” he says. “Any given
amount of QE today probably has a smaller impact on asset prices than it would
have had three, four, five years ago.”
For Fels, that is not an argument
against QE. Although its effect is diminishing, it is not zero, let alone
negative. In his view, the answer is for central banks to inject even more
liquidity into the system.
Perhaps the most radical critique
comes from Michael Howell, the founder of Cross-Border Capital, a consultancy
established in 1996 with the specific goal of monitoring global capital flows.
In his view, the markets have largely failed to recognise a fundamental shift
in the nature of financial intermediation over the years.
In the traditional textbook model,
central banks provide reserves to the system which are then taken up by commercial
banks. In turn, the commercial banks lend to industrial and other enterprises.
However, Howell argues, the
situation has shifted fundamentally as many non-financial companies are awash
with cash. Therefore, they are using their spare liquidity in other ways, such
as buying back shares or engaging in mergers and acquisitions, rather than
depositing their money in banks.
“The polarity of the financial
system has reversed,” he says. “Industrial corporations are no longer borrowers
from banks – they are effectively lenders into the system.”
As a result, banks no longer play
their traditional role. “They have been disintermediated out of the system,” he
says.
Howell argues that three elements
have replaced the traditional role of bank reserves and loans. First, are new
suppliers of funds. These include QE from central banks and money direct from
corporates.
Second, the stock of collateral
available in the system. For Howell the supply and demand for collateral plays
a key role in determining the extend of liquidity in the financial
system.
Finally, there is the collateral
haircut. That is an adjustment to the market value of collateral designed to
reflect the risk of not realising the quoted market value of securities.
In Howell’s view, several factors
are acting to reduce liquidity in this new model financial system. These
include threats to corporate earnings, the prospect of a Fed rate rise and a
decline in the available pool of Treasuries.
‘QE can
work if conducted with the right logic’
Professor
Hans-Werner Sinn
is the president of the IFO Institute in Munich and one of Germany’s most
prominent economists. His latest book, Der Euro: Von der Friedensidee zum
Zankapfel (The Euro: From Peace Project to Bone of Contention), has just been
published by Hanser. Daniel
Ben-Ami quizzed him about the pros and cons
of quantitative easing at this year’s Uhlenbruch conference in Zurich
Q: What do you see as the impact
of quantitative easing (QE) on the US?
QE has rescued lots of banks. It has
rescued some economies because lots of liquidity was made available for
investment in old and new assets. House prices have recovered and unemployment
has been reduced enormously. The dollar also devalued after QE, which also gave
a boost to the American economy. So, in principle, QE worked. As [former US
Federal Reserve chair Ben] Bernanke said, we don’t know why it worked, but it
worked.
Professor Hans-Werner Sinn
It also worked in Britain. But it
didn’t work in Japan – it did lead to a devaluation of the yen but the economy
didn’t really get going. So Abenomics was a failure.
The question is what will happen
with European QE? In theory, I think it’s good for the economy because through
a devaluation it will inflate the euro-zone and allow southern Europe to stay
behind and let Germany inflate away. That way, southern Europe will regain
competitiveness and reduce some of its real debt. However, for regaining
competitiveness, southern Europe has to stop taking Keynesian drugs. This, I
think, is the economic rationale behind QE, which I endorse.
The point is, though, until now, we
haven’t seen much of an increase in inflation in Germany. We have seen an
increase in the core inflation rate for Europe, on average, but a symmetric
increase in inflation everywhere is useless because we have a flexible exchange
rate with the non-euro countries. What the euro-zone needs is a differential
inflation in the north, while the south stays behind. It’s not yet clear
whether this will be happening to a sufficient extent.
Q: Do you see any downside to QE?
The downside is that it’s possibly
creating a bubble, or preventing the bursting of one, by keeping asset prices
high. It’s delaying the necessary bankruptcies in the banking sector. The ECB
[European Central Bank] seems to try to delay these bankruptcies until the
banking union allows for a socialisation of the losses. On the other hand,
differential inflation is the only way out for the southern European
countries.
Q: How can worries about
liquidity drying up coincide with central banks pumping large amounts into the
economy?
The problem is that firms in the
real economy don’t have easy access to credit finance. given the fragile state
of their respective economies. The ECB hopes that by buying government bonds to
increase liquidity it will lead to more bank lending to companies but this is
unlikely to succeed.
If the ECB wants to improve
the financing condition of companies it should not buy government bonds but
corporate bonds or ABS [asset backed security] paper which is created out of
credit claims of banks on private companies.
Q: So you think it’s the way that
the ECB is conducting QE that is the problem?
Yes, it’s a circumvention. If I want
you to have easy finance I should give you a credit, rather than giving it to a
rival or your neighbour. That’s what the ECB does by buying government bonds.
It allows governments to borrow more easily and hopes that the private sector
can therefore also borrow more easily. That’s a logic which is not easily
understandable.
Under this system, QE can also mean
buying Treasuries from the financial system. Ironically, such action can mean
taking liquidity from the financial system before giving it back again. “A lot
of the time the central banks’ QE is a zero-sum game,” says Howell. “They are taking
with one hand and giving with the other”. If he is right, it goes a long way to
explaining why QE is having a diminishing effect.
“Do not
confuse low interest rates with easy money”
Chen Zhao
Chen Zhao
Before drawing to a close, it should
be noted that there are some who even reject the premise that central bank
liquidity is plentiful. For example, Chen Zhao, co-director of Global Macro
Research at Brandywine Global, says that, despite appearances, US monetary
policy is tight at present. In his view, the strength of the dollar, in effect,
amounts to a monetary tightening. “Do not confuse low interest rates with easy
money,” he says.
Conclusion
It should be clear, then, that central banks can have a substantial impact on asset prices. There is also a reasonable argument, accepted by many, that they have a significant influence on market liquidity.
It should be clear, then, that central banks can have a substantial impact on asset prices. There is also a reasonable argument, accepted by many, that they have a significant influence on market liquidity.
Ironically, the impact of regulatory
action can work in the opposite direction. It is widely accepted that the trend
towards the stricter regulation of financial institutions has played a
significant role in tightening liquidity at times.
Central banks have played their role
in playing down the threat of liquidity drying up. In their view the threat is
exaggerated. But this view, while important to consider, should be treated with
a degree of scepticism as one of their roles is to calm the markets.
For asset managers themselves there
are some things they can do to mitigate the impact of a liquidity shock.
Demanding a higher compensation for illiquid assets is one obvious step.
Placing greater emphasis on credit quality is another. In any event, long-term
investors should be less vulnerable than short-term ones.
Ultimately, though, the authorities
may have to play an active role in resolving any difficulties. The authorities
are no doubt well-intentioned but their actions seem to be pushing the markets
in contradictory directions at present.
The topic will be one to watch
closely in 2016.
No comments:
Post a Comment